Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  6 / 20 Next Page
Basic version Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 6 / 20 Next Page
Page Background

6(20)

An additional question is the consequences on take-up rates when the

individuals do not have full information of the detection probability. If

individuals update their probability of being detected misusing the

insurance when being monitored this would reduce the take-up probability

later on given that there is a deterrence effect.

2

This would result in a

form of equilibrium effect from monitoring. In contrast, if the detection

probability was known the individual’s future take-up of the insurance

would not be affected by being monitored today even if a deterrence effect

exists. Furthermore if there is no deterrence effect then the updating of

probabilities of detection will not affect future take up either.

There is some support of this type of equilibrium effect through the

updating of probabilities of being monitored in the SI literature. Johansson

and Lindahl (2013) find that screening affects future take-up rates of

sickness benefits. de Jong et al., (2011) finds that that the increased

screening in the SI program reduce the applications to the disability

insurance program. This effect is denoted self screening in de Jong et al.

(2011).

This paper studies the existence of an equilibrium effect of monitoring or

self screening by using data from the Swedish temporary parental benefit

program. The program is well suited to test for an equilibrium effect on

insurance programs as the frequency of using the insurance is high. In

addition we have the advantage that the SSIA picks out parents randomly

to be monitored which enables us to estimate the effects of being randomly

assigned to be monitored on future (up to one year after the assignment)

temporary parental leave payments. If individuals do not know the

probability of detection but make inferences about the probability of the

detection by using heuristic rules, e.g. based on their own experience then

they are likely to "overestimate" the probability of detection some time

period after being monitored even when the level of monitoring is constant,

which is the case for the program in the studied period.

The temporary parental benefit compensates for the loss of earnings

when staying at home from work to take care of a sick child (below the

age of 12). In the SI program the employer pays the sickness benefits

the first fourteen days and there is one waiting day before receiving the

compensation, while there is none in the temporary parental benefit

program. Both the employer period and the waiting day gives monetary

incentives of using the insurance for the parents own illness.

3

In order to

claim benefits from the insurance parents simply report that the child is ill

to the Swedish Social Insurance Agency (SSIA). This implies that parents

could claim for benefits for own illness but also as a means of increasing

incomes, that is, they can work and let the child attend day care or school

during the claimed benefit period. The sanctions when misusing the system

are small or not existing and the degree of monitoring or screening is low

(around 5 percent of all claims). It is hence very likely that any finding of

an economic significant equilibrium effect could be carried over to other

programs with less lenient sanctions and to programs with more

monitoring.

2

This prediction builds on the idea of bounded rationality, that is, we humans make

decisions based on probabilities that are estimated using simple heuristic rules (cf.

Kahneman (2003)).

3

Since the cap in the temporary insurance is lower than the cap in the sickness

insurance the incentives differ across individuals. The incentives may be the

opposite for high income individuals who expect to be long term absent.